SEARCH

SEARCH BY CITATION

References

  • Allen, R. C., and M. Gisser (1984), Competition versus optimal control in groundwater pumping when demand is nonlinear, Water Resour. Res., 20, 752756.
  • Anderson, T. L., O. R. Burt, and D. T. Fractor (1983), Privatizing groundwater basins: A model and its application, in Water Rights: Scarce Resource Allocation, Bureaucracy, and the Environment, edited by T. L. Anderson, pp. 116, Pac. Res. Inst. for Public Policy, San Francisco, Calif.
  • Bernardo, D. J., N. K. Whittlesey, K. E. Saxton, and D. L. Bassett (1987), An irrigation model for management of limited water supplies, West. J. Agric. Econ., 12, 164173.
  • Bontemps, C., S. Couture, and P. Favard (2004), Is irrigation water demand really convex? in Econometrics Informing Natural Resource Management: Selected Case Studies, edited by P. Koundouri, Edward Elgar, Northampton, Mass., in press.
  • Bredehoeft, J. D., and R. A. Young (1970), The temporal allocation of ground water: A simulation approach, Water Resour. Res., 6, 321.
  • Brill, T. S., and H. S. Burness (1994), Planning versus competitive rates of groundwater pumping, Water Resour. Res., 30, 18731880.
  • Brown, B.,Jr. (1974), An optimal program for managing common property resources with congestion externalities, J. Polit. Econ., 82, 163173.
  • Brown, G., and R. Deacon (1972), Economic optimization of a single cell aquifer, Water Resour. Res., 8, 552564.
  • Burness, H. S., and T. C. Brill (1992), The role for policy in common pool groundwater use, Resour. Energy Econ., 23, 1940.
  • Burness, H. S., and T. C. Brill (2001), The role for policy in common pool groundwater use, Resour. Energy Econ., 23(1), 1940.
  • Burness, H. S., and W. E. Martin (1988), Management of a tributary aquifer, Water Resour. Res., 24, 13391344.
  • Burt, O. R. (1964), Optimal resource use over time with an application to groundwater, Manage. Sci., 11, 8093.
  • Burt, O. R. (1966), Economic control of ground water reserves, J. Farm Econ., 48, 632647.
  • Burt, O. R. (1967), Temporal allocation of groundwater, Water Resour. Res., 3, 4556.
  • Burt, O. R. (1970), Groundwater storage control under institutional restrictions, Water Resour. Res., 6, 15401548.
  • Cummings, R. G., and J. W. McFarland (1973), Groundwater management and salinity control, Am. J. Agric. Econ., 56, 830836.
  • Dasgupta, P. S., and G. M. Heal (1979), Economic Theory and Exhaustible Resources, Cambridge Univ. Press, New York.
  • Dixon, L. S. (1989), Models of groundwater extraction with an examination of agricultural water use in Kern County, California, Ph.D. dissertation, Univ. of Calif., Berkeley.
  • Dockner, E. J., and N. V. Long (1993), International pollution control: Cooperative versus noncooperative strategies, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 24, 1329.
  • Feinerman, E., and K. C. Knapp (1983), Benefits from groundwater management: Magnitude, sensitivity, and distribution, Am. J. Agric. Econ., 65, 703710.
  • Garrido, A., C. Varela-Ortega, and J. M. Sumpsi (1997), The interaction of agricultural pricing policies and water districts' modernization programs: A question with unexpected answers, paper presented at the 8th Conference of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, Tilburg, Netherlands, 28–29 June.
  • Gisser, M. (1983), Groundwater: Focusing on the real issue, J. Polit. Econ., 91, 10011028.
  • Gisser, M., and A. Mercado (1972), Integration of the agricultural demand functions for water and the hydrologic model of the Pecos Basin, Water Resour. Res., 8, 13731384.
  • Gisser, M., and A. Mercado (1973), Economic aspects of ground water resources and replacement flows in semiarid agricultural areas, Am. J. Agric. Econ., 55, 461466.
  • Gisser, M., and D. A. Sánchez (1980a), Some additional economic aspects of ground water resources replacement flows in semi-arid agricultural areas, Int. Control, J., 31(2), 331341.
  • Gisser, M., and D. A. Sánchez (1980b), Competition versus optimal control in groundwater pumping, Water Resour. Res., 16, 638642.
  • Groom, B., P. Koundouri, and T. Swanson (2003), The watershed economics management approach: An application to Cyprus, in Economics of Water Management in Developing Countries: Problems, Principles and Policies, edited by P. Koundouri et al., pp. 181214, Edward Elgar, Northampton, Mass.
  • Groom, B., P. Koundouri, and T. Swanson (2004), Integrated resource management in Cyprus, in Cost-Benefit Analysis and Water Resources Management, edited by R. Brouwer, and D. Pearce, Kluwer Acad., Norwell, Mass., in press.
  • Howitt, R. (1995), Positive mathematical programming, Am. J. Agric., 77, 329342.
  • Howitt, R. E., W. D. Watson, and R. M. Adams (1980), A reevaluation of price elasticities for irrigation water, Water Resour. Res., 16, 623628.
  • Iglesias, E., A. Garrido, J. Sumpsi, and C. Varela-Ortega (1998), Water demand elasticity: Implications for water management and water pricing policies, paper presented at the World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, Eur. Assoc. of Environ. and Resour. Econ., Venice, Italy, 26–28 June.
  • Kelso, M. M. (1961), The stock resource value of water, J. Farm Econ., 43(5), 11121129.
  • Kim, C. S., M. R. Moore, and J. J. Hanchar (1989), A dynamic model of adaptation to resource depletion: Theory and an application to groundwater mining, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 17, 6682.
  • Knapp, K. C., and L. J. Olson (1995), The Economics of conjunctive groundwater management with stochastic surface supplies, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 28, 340356.
  • Knapp, K. C., and L. J. Olson (1996), Dynamic resource management: Intertemporal substitution and risk aversion, Am. J. Agric. Econ., 78, 10041014.
  • Koundouri, P. (2000), Three approaches to measuring natural resource scarcity: Theory and application to groundwater, Ph.D. thesis, Fac. of Econ. and Polit., Univ. of Cambridge, Cambridge, U. K.
  • Koundouri, P. (2003), Contrasting different methodologies to deriving natural resource scarcity rents, in Economics of Water Management in Developing Countries: Problems, Principles and Policies, edited by P. Koundouri et al., pp. 157178, Edward Elgar, Northampton, Mass.
  • Koundouri, P., and C. Christou (2000), Dynamic adaptation to resource scarcity with backstop availability, paper presented at the Tenth Annual Conference, Eur. Assoc. of Environ. and Resour. Econ., Rethymnon, Greece, June.
  • Koundouri, P., and P. Pashardes (2002), Hedonic price snalysis and selectivity bias: Water salinity and demand for land, Environ. Resour. Econ., 23(2), 4556.
  • Koundouri, P., and A. Xepapadeas (2003), A new methodology to measuring groundwater scarcity: Theory and application, in Economics of Water Management in Developing Countries: Problems, Principles and Policies, edited by P. Koundouri et al., pp. 134156, Edward Elgar, Northampton, Mass.
  • Koundouri, P., and A. Xepapadeas (2004), Estimating accounting prices for common pool natural resources: A distance function approach, Water Resour. Res., 40, W06S17, doi:10.1029/2003WR002170, in press.
  • Kydland, F. E., and E. C. Prescott (1977), Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans, J. Polit. Econ., 85, 473491.
  • Lee, K. C., C. Short, and E. O. Heady (1981), Optimal groundwater mining in the Ogallala Aquifer: Estimation of economic losses and excessive depletion due to commonality, report, Cent. for Agric. and Rural Dev., Iowa State Univ., Ames.
  • Milliman, J. W. (1956), Commonality, the price system and the use of water supplies, Soc. Econ. J., 22, 426437.
  • Montginoul, M., and T. Rieut (1996), Instruments economiques et gestion de l'eau d'irrigation en France, Houille Blanche, 8, 4754.
  • Negri, D. H. (1989), The common property aquifer as a differential game, Water Resour. Res., 25, 915.
  • Nieswiadomy, M. (1985), The demand for irrigation water in the High Plains of Texas, 1957–1980, Am. J. Agric. Econ., 67(3), 619626.
  • Noel, J. E., B. D. Gardner, and C. V. Moore (1980), Optimal regional conjunctive water management, Am. J. Agric. Econ., 62, 489498.
  • Pearce, D., B. Groom, C. Hepburn, and P. Koundouri (2003), Valuing the uture: Recent advances in social discounting, World Econ., 4(2), 121141.
  • Provencher, B. (1993), A private property rights regime to replenish a groundwater aquifer, Land Econ., 69(4), 325340.
  • Provencher, B., and O. Burt (1993), The externalities associated with the common property exploitation of groundwater, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 24, 139158.
  • Provencher, B., and O. Burt (1994), A private property rights regime for the commons: The case for groundwater, Am. J. Agric., 875888.
  • Renshaw, E. F. (1963), The management of ground water reservoirs, J. Farm Econ., 45(2), 285295.
  • Roseta-Palma, C. (2002), Groundwater management and endogenous water quality, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 44, 93105.
  • Rubio, S., and B. Casino (2004), Strategic behaviour and efficiency in the common property extraction of groundwater, Environ. Resour. Econ, in press.
  • Shah, F. A., D. Zilberman, and U. Chakravorty (1995), Technology adoption in the presence of an exhaustible resource: The case of groundwater extraction, Am. J. Agric. Econ., 77(2), 291299.
  • Shunway, C. R. (1973), Derived demand for irrigation water: The California aqueduct, Southwest. J. Agric. Econ., 5, 195200.
  • Smith, V. L. (1977), Water deeds: A proposed solution to the water valuation problem, Ariz. Rev., 26, 710.
  • Tsur, Y. (1990), The stabilization role of groundwater when surface water supplies are uncertain: The implications for groundwater development, Water Resour. Res., 26, 811818.
  • Tsur, Y., and T. Graham-Tomasi (1991), The buffer value of groundwater with stochastic surface water supplies, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 21, 201224.
  • Tsur, Y., and A. Zemel (1995), Uncertainty and irreversibility in groundwater resource management, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 29, 149161.
  • Tsutsui, S., and K. Mino (1990), Nonlinear strategies in dynamic duopolistic competition with sticky prices, J. Econ. Theory, 52, 136161.
  • Varela-Ortega, C., J. M. Sumpsi, A. Garrido, M. Blanco, and E. Iglesias (1998), Water pricing policies, public decision making and farmers' response: Implications for water policy, Agric. Econ., 19, 193202.
  • Wirl, F. (1994), The Ramsey model revisited: The optimality of cyclical consumption and growth, J. Econ., 60, 8198.
  • Wirl, F., and E. Dockner (1995), Leviathan governments and carbon taxes: Costs and potential benefits, Eur. Econ. Rev., 39, 12151236.
  • Worthington, V. E., O. R. Burt, and R. L. Brustkern (1985), Optimal management of a confined aquifer system, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 12, 229245.
  • Young, R. A., and J. D. Bredehoeft (1972), Digital computer simulation for solving management problems of conjunctive groundwater and surface water systems, Water Resour. Res., 8, 533556.
  • Zimmerman, W. R. (1990), Finite hydraulic conductivity effects on optimal groundwater pumping rates, Water Resour. Res., 26, 28612864.