SEARCH

SEARCH BY CITATION

References

  • Agthe, D. E., and R. B. Billings (1987), Equity, price elasticity, and household income under increasing block rates for water, Am. J. Econ. Sociol., 46(3), 273286, doi:10.1111/j.1536-7150.1987.tb01966.x.
  • Aher, A., A. Chouthai, L. Chandrasekar, W. Corpening, L. Russ, and B. Vijapur (1991), East Bay Municipal Utility District water conservation study, Stevens Inst. of Technol., Oakland, Calif.
  • Aquacraft Water Engineering and Management (1996), Project report: Measuring actual retrofit savings and conservation effectiveness using flow trace analysis, Utilities Div. Off. of Water Conserv., Boulder, Colo.
  • Baumann, D. D., J. J. Boland, and J. H. Sims (1984), Water conservation: The struggle over definition, Water Resour. Res., 20(4), 428434, doi:10.1029/WR020i004p00428.
  • Baumol, W. J., and W. E. Oates (1988), The Theory of Environmental Policy, 2nd ed., 299 pp., Cambridge Univ. Press, New York.
  • Bennear, L. S., and R. N. Stavins (2007), Second-best theory and the use of multiple policy instruments, Environ. Resour. Econ., 37, 111129, doi:10.1007/s10640-007-9110-y.
  • Bernstein, M. A., and J. Griffin (2005), Regional differences in the price elasticity of demand for energy, technical report, RAND, Santa Monica, Calif.
  • Biermayer, P. J. (2005), Potential water and energy savings from showerheads, Rep. LBNL-58601, Environ. Energy Technol. Div., Lawrence Berkeley Natl. Lab., Berkeley, Calif., 28 Sept.
  • Bohi, D. R., and M. B. Zimmerman (1984), An update on econometric studies of energy demand behavior, Annu. Rev. Energy, 9, 105154, doi:10.1146/annurev.eg.09.110184.000541.
  • Boland, J. J., and D. Whittington (2000), The political economy of water tariff design in developing countries: Increasing block tariffs versus uniform price with rebate, in The Political Economy of Water Pricing Reforms, edited by A. Dinar, pp. 215235, Oxford Univ. Press, New York.
  • Brennan, D., S. Tapsuwan, and G. Ingram (2007), The welfare costs of urban outdoor water restrictions, Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ., 51, 243261, doi:10.1111/j.1467-8489.2007.00395.x.
  • Brewer, J., R. Glennon, A. Ker, and G. Libecap (2007), Transferring water in the American West: 1987–2005, Univ. Mich. Law Reform, J., 40(4), 10211053.
  • Brown, T. C. (2006), Trends in water market activity and price in the western United States, Water Resour. Res., 42, W09402, doi:10.1029/2005WR004180.
  • Collinge, R. A. (1994), Transferable rate entitlements: The overlooked opportunity in municipal water pricing, Public Finance Rev., 22(1), 4664.
  • Corral, L. R. (1997), Price and non-price influence in urban water conservation, Ph.D. dissertation, 90 pp., Univ. of Calif., Berkeley.
  • Crocker, T. D. (1966), The structuring of atmospheric pollution control systems, in The Economics of Air Pollution, edited by H. Wolozin, pp. 6186, Norton, New York.
  • Dales, J. (1968), Pollution, Property and Prices, 111 pp., Univ. Press, Toronto, Ont., Canada.
  • Dalhuisen, J. M., R. J. G. M. Florax, H. L. F. de Groot, and P. Nijkamp (2003), Price and income elasticities of residential water demand: A meta-analysis, Land Econ., 79(2), 292308, doi:10.2307/3146872.
  • Davis, L. W. (2008), Durable goods and residential demand for energy and water: Evidence from a field trial, RAND J. Econ., 39(2), 530546.
  • Dixon, L. S., N. Y. Moore, and E. M. Pint (1996), Drought Management Policies and Economic Effects in Urban Areas of California, 1987–1992, 131 pp., RAND, Santa Monica, Calif.
  • Downing, P. B., and L. J. White (1986), Innovation in pollution control, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 13, 1829, doi:10.1016/0095-0696(86)90014-8.
  • Espey, M., J. Espey, and W. D. Shaw (1997), Price elasticity of residential demand for water: A meta-analysis, Water Resour. Res., 33(6), 13691374, doi:10.1029/97WR00571.
  • Gaudin, S. (2006), Effect of price information on residential water demand, Appl. Econ., 38, 383393, doi:10.1080/00036840500397499.
  • Gibbons, D. C. (1986), The Economic Value of Water, Resour. for the Future, Washington, D. C.
  • Grafton, R. Q., and M. Ward (2008), Prices versus rationing: Marshallian surplus and mandatory water restrictions, Econ. Rec., 84, S57S65, doi:10.1111/j.1475-4932.2008.00483.x.
  • Greening, L. A., D. L. Greene, and C. Difiglio (2000), Energy efficiency and consumption–the rebound effect—A survey, Energy Policy, 28(6–7), 389401, doi:10.1016/S0301-4215(00)00021-5.
  • Griffin, R. C. (2006), Water Resource Economics: The Analysis of Scarcity, Policies and Projects, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.
  • Hall, D. C. (2000), Public choice and water rate design, in The Political Economy of Water Pricing Reforms, edited by A. Dinar, pp. 189212, Oxford Univ. Press, New York.
  • Hanemann, W. M. (1997), Price and rate structures, in Urban Water Demand Management and Planning, edited by D. D. Baumann et al., pp. 137179, McGraw-Hill, New York.
  • Hewitt, J. A. (2000), An investigation into the reasons why water utilities choose particular residential rate structures, in The Political Economy of Water Pricing Reforms, edited by A. Dinar, pp. 259277, Oxford Univ. Press, New York.
  • Howe, C. W. (1997), Increasing efficiency in water markets: Examples from the western United States, in Water Marketing—The Next Generation, edited by T. L. Anderson, and P. J. Hill, pp. 79100, Rowman and Littlefield, Lanham, Md.
  • Hutson, S. S., N. L. Barber, J. F. Kenny, K. S. Linsey, D. S. Lumia, and M. A. Maupin (2004), Estimated use of water in the United States in 2000, U.S. Geol. Surv., 1268.
  • Keohane, N. O. (2005), Environmental policy and the choice of abatement technique: Evidence from coal-fired electric power plants, working paper, Yale Univ., New Haven, Conn.
  • Keohane, N. O. (2007), Cost savings from allowance trading in the 1990 Clean Air Act, in Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation: Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience, edited by C. E. Kolstad, and J. Freeman, pp. 194230, Oxford Univ. Press, New York.
  • Keohane, N. O., and S. M. Olmstead (2007), Markets and the Environment, Island, Washington, D. C.
  • Keohane, N. O., R. L. Revesz, and R. N. Stavins (1998), The choice of regulatory instruments in environmental policy, Harvard Environ. Law Rev., 22(2), 313367.
  • Kiefer, J. C., B. Dziegielewski, and E. M. Opitz (1993), Analysis of water savings from the LITEBILL program: An evaluation of alternative research methods, Plann. and Manage. Consult., Ltd., Carbondale, Ill.
  • Kolstad, C. E., and J. Freeman (Eds.) (2007), Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation: Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience, Oxford Univ. Press, New York.
  • Krause, K., J. M. Chermak, and D. S. Brookshire (2003), The demand for water: Consumer response to scarcity, J. Regul. Econ., 23(2), 167191, doi:10.1023/A:1022207030378.
  • Kulshreshtha, S. N. (1996), Residential water demand in Saskatchewan communities: Role played by block pricing system in water conservation, Can. Water Resour. J., 21, 139155.
  • Mansur, E. T., and S. M. Olmstead (2007), The value of scarce water: Measuring the inefficiency of municipal regulations, Working Pap. 13513, Natl. Bur. of Econ. Res., Cambridge, Mass.
  • Mayer, P. W., W. B. DeOreo, E. M. Opitz, J. C. Kiefer, W. Y. Davis, B. Dziegielewski, and J. O. Nelson (1998), Residential End Uses of Water, Am. Water Works Assoc. Res. Found., Denver, Colo.
  • Michelsen, A. M., J. T. McGuckin, and D. M. Stumpf (1998), Effectiveness of Residential Water Conservation Price and Nonprice Programs, 128 pp., Am. Water Works Assoc. Res. Found., Denver, Colo.
  • Milliman, S. R., and R. Prince (1989), Firm incentives to promote technological change in pollution control, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 17, 247265, doi:10.1016/0095-0696(89)90019-3.
  • Montgomery, D. (1972), Markets in licenses and efficient pollution control programs, J. Econ. Theory, 5, 395418, doi:10.1016/0022-0531(72)90049-X.
  • Munasinghe, M. (1992), Water Supply and Environmental Management: Developing World Applications, Westview, Boulder, Colo.
  • Olmstead, S. M., W. M. Hanemann, and R. N. Stavins (2007), Water demand under alternative price structures, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 54(2), 181198, doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2007.03.002.
  • Panayotou, T. (1998), Instruments of Change: Motivating and Financing Sustainable Development, 228 pp., Earthscan, London.
  • Pigou, A. C. (1920), The Economics of Welfare, Macmillan, London.
  • Rausser, G. C. (2000), Collective choice in water resource systems, in The Political Economy of Water Pricing Reforms, edited by A. Dinar, pp. 4978, Oxford Univ. Press, New York.
  • Renwick, M. E., and S. O. Archibald (1998), Demand side management policies for residential water use: Who bears the conservation burden? Land Econ., 74(3), 343359, doi:10.2307/3147117.
  • Renwick, M. E., and R. D. Green (2000), Do residential water demand side management policies measure up? An analysis of eight California water agencies, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 40(1), 3755, doi:10.1006/jeem.1999.1102.
  • Renzetti, S. (1992a), Estimating the structure of industrial water demands: The case of Canadian manufacturing, Land Econ., 68(4), 396404, doi:10.2307/3146696.
  • Renzetti, S. (1992b), Evaluating the welfare effects of reforming municipal water prices, J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 22(2), 147163, doi:10.1016/0095-0696(92)90011-K.
  • Renzetti, S. (1999), Municipal water supply and sewage treatment: Costs, prices and distortions, Can. J. Econ., 32, 688704, doi:10.2307/136444.
  • Renzetti, S. (Ed.) (2002), Economics of Industrial Water Use, Edward Elgar, London.
  • Reynaud, A. (2003), An econometric estimation of industrial water demand in France, Environ. Resour. Econ., 25, 213232, doi:10.1023/A:1023992322236.
  • Russell, C., and B. Shin (1996a), An application and evaluation of competing marginal cost pricing approximations, in Marginal Cost Rate Design and Wholesale Water Markets, Adv. Econ. Environ. Resour., vol. 1, edited by D. Hall, pp. 141164, JAI Press, Greenwich, Conn.
  • Russell, C., and B. Shin (1996b), Public utility pricing: Theory and practical limitations, in Marginal Cost Rate Design and Wholesale Water Markets, Adv. Econ. Environ. Resour., vol. 1, edited by D. Hall, pp. 123139, JAI Press, Greenwich, Conn.
  • Schultz, M. T., S. M. Cavanagh, B. Gu, and D. J. Eaton (1997), The consequences of water consumption restrictions during the Corpus Christi drought of 1996, draft report, Lyndon B. Johnson Sch. of Public Affairs, Univ. of Tex. at Austin, Austin.
  • Sibly, H. (2006), Efficient urban water pricing, Aust. Econ. Rev., 39, 227237, doi:10.1111/j.1467-8462.2006.00415.x.
  • Stavins, R. N. (2003), Market-based environmental policy instruments, in Handbook of Environmental Economics, vol. 1, Environmental Degradation and Institutional Responses, edited by K.-G. Mäler, and J. R. Vincent, pp. 355435, Elsevier Sci., Amsterdam.
  • Sterner, T. (2003), Policy Instruments for Environmental and Natural Resource Management, 504 pp., Resour. for the Future, Washington, D. C.
  • Teitenberg, T. (2006), Emissions Trading: Principles and Practice, 2nd ed., 231 pp., Resour. for the Future, Washington, D. C.
  • Timmins, C. (2002), Does the median voter consume too much water? Analyzing the redistributive role of residential water bills, Natl. Tax J., 55(4), 687702.
  • Timmins, C. (2003), Demand-side technology standards under inefficient pricing regimes: Are they effective water conservation tools in the long run? Environ. Resour. Econ., 26, 107124, doi:10.1023/A:1025689706396.
  • U.S. General Accounting Office (2000), Water infrastructure: Water-efficient plumbing fixtures reduce water consumption and wastewater flows, Rep. GAO/RCED-00-232, Washington, D. C.
  • Weitzman, M. L. (1974), Prices vs. quantities, Rev. Econ. Stud., 41(4), 477491, doi:10.2307/2296698.
  • Ziegler, J. A., and S. E. Bell (1984), Estimating demand for intake water by self-supplied firms, Water Resour. Res., 20(1), 48, doi:10.1029/WR020i001p00004.