SEARCH

SEARCH BY CITATION

References

  • Akers, R.L. (1985). Deviant behavior: a social learning approach. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth.
  • Anderson, L.G. (1987). A management agency perspective of the economics of fisheries regulation. Mar. Res. Econ. 4, 123131.
  • Anderson, L.G. & Lee, D.R. (1986). Optimal governing instrument, operation level, and enforcement in natural-resource regulation – the case of the fishery. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 68, 678690.
  • Andreozzi, L. (2004). Rewarding policeman increases crime. Another surprising result from the inspection game. Public Choice 121, 6982.
  • Arcese, P., Hando, J. & Campbell, K. (1995). Historical and present-day anti-poaching efforts in Serengeti. In Serengeti II. Dynamics, management, and conservation of an ecosystem: 506533. Sinclair, A.R.E. & Arcese, P. (Eds). Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.
  • Axelrod, R. & Hamilton, W.D. (1981). The evolution of cooperation. Science 211, 13901396.
  • Balmford, A., Bruner, A., Cooper, P., Costanza, R., Farber, S., Green, R.E., Jenkins, M., Jefferiss, P., Jessamy, V., Madden, J., Munro, K., Myers, N., Naeem, S., Paavola, J., Rayment, M., Rosendo, S., Roughgarden, J., Trumper, K. & Turner, R.K. (2002). Economic reasons for conserving wild nature. Science 297, 950953.
  • Balmford, A. & Whitten, T. (2003). Who should pay for tropical conservation, and how could the costs be met? Oryx 37, 238.
  • Bebchuk, L.A. & Kaplow, L. (1992). Optimal sanctions when individuals are imperfectly informed about the probability of apprehension. J. Leg. Stud. 21, 365370.
  • Becker, G.S. (1968). Crime and punishment: an economic approach. J. Polit. Econ. 76, 169217.
  • Becker, G.S. & Stigler, G.J. (1974). Law enforcement, malfeasance, and compensation of enforcers. J. Leg. Stud. 3, 118.
  • Bowen-Jones, E., Brown, D. & Robinson, E.J.Z. (2003). Economic commodity or environmental crisis? An interdisciplinary approach to analysing the bushmeat trade in central and west Africa. Area 35, 390402.
  • Bulte, E.H., Damania, R. & Van Kooten, G.C. (2007). The effects of one-off ivory sales on elephant mortality. Wildl. Mgmt. 71, 613618.
  • Bulte, E.H., Horan, R.D. & Shogren, J.F. (2003). Elephants: comment. Am. Econ. Rev. 93, 14371445.
  • Bulte, E.H. & Van Kooten, G.C. (1999). Economics of antipoaching enforcement and the ivory trade ban. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 81, 453466.
  • Burgess, R. & Akers, R.L. (1966). A differential association-reinforcement theory of criminal behavior. Soc. Probl. 14, 128147.
  • Cameron, S. (1988). The economics of crime deterrence: a survey of theory and evidence. Kyklos 41, 301.
  • Chan, K.M.A., Pringle, R.M., Ranganathan, J.A.I., Boggs, C.L., Chan, Y.L., Ehrlich, P.R., Haff, P.K., Heller, N.E., Al-Khafaji, K. & Macmynowski, D.P. (2007). When agendas collide: human welfare and biological conservation. Conserv. Biol. 21, 5968.
  • Clark, C.W. (1973). Profit maximization and extinction of animal species. J. Polit. Econ. 81, 950961.
  • Clark, C.W. (1990). Mathematical bioeconomics: the optimal management of renewable resources. John Wiley & Sons Inc, New York.
  • Clayton, L., Keeling, M. & Milner-Gulland, E.J. (1997). Bringing home the bacon: a spatial model of wild pig hunting in Sulawesi, Indonesia. Ecol. Appl. 7, 642652.
  • Conlisk, J. (1996). Why bounded rationality? J. Econ. Literature 34, 669700.
  • Damania, R., Milner-Gulland, E.J. & Crookes, D.J. (2005). A bioeconomic analysis of bushmeat hunting. Proc. Roy. Soc. B – Biol. Sci. 272, 259266.
  • Dawes, R.M. (1973). The commons dilemma game: an n-person mixed-motive game with a dominating strategy for defection. Oregon Res. Inst. J. 13, 112.
  • Edwards-Jones, G. (2006). Modelling farmer decision-making: concepts, progress and challenges. Anim. Sci. 82, 783790.
  • Ehrlich, I. (1996). Crime, punishment, and the market for offences. J. Econ. Perspect. 10, 4367.
  • Fehr, E. & Gachter, S. (2002). Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415, 137140.
  • Floeter, S.R., Halpern, B.S. & Ferreira, C.E.L. (2006). Effects of fishing and protection on Brazilian reef fishes. Biol. Conserv. 128, 391402.
  • Fowler, J.H. (2005). Altruistic punishment and the origin of cooperation. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 102, 70477049.
  • Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G. & O'Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: a critical review. J. Econ. Literature 40, 351401.
  • Furlong, W.J. (1991). The deterrent effect of regulatory enforcement in the fishery. Land Econ. 67, 116.
  • Gelcich, S., Edwards-Jones, G., Kaiser, M.J. & Castilla, J.C. (2006). Co-management policy can reduce resilience in traditionally managed marine ecosystems. Ecosystems 9, 951966.
  • Gezelius, S.S. (2002). Do norms count? State regulation and compliance in a Norwegian fishing community. Acta Sociol. 45, 305314.
  • Gezelius, S.S. (2004). Food, money, and morals: compliance among natural resource harvesters. Hum. Ecol. 32, 615634.
  • Gibson, C.C., Williams, J.T. & Ostrom, E. (2005). Local enforcement and better forests. World Dev. 33, 273284.
  • Goslin, P.D. (1969). Handbook of socialization theory and research. New York: Rand McNally.
  • Hallwood, P. (2005). Protected areas, optimal policing and optimal rent dissipation. Mar. Res. Econ. 19, 481493.
  • Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science 162, 1243.
  • Hatcher, A. & Gordon, D. (2005). Further investigations into the factors affecting compliance with UK fishing quotas. Land Econ. 81, 7186.
  • Hatcher, A., Jaffry, S., Thébaud, O. & Bennett, E. (2000). Normative and social influences affecting compliance with fishery regulations. Land Econ. 76, 448.
  • Heckathorn, D.D. (1996). The dynamics and dilemmas of collective action. Am. Sociol. Rev. 61, 250277.
  • Hilborn, R., Arcese, P., Borner, M., Hando, J., Hopcraft, G., Loibooki, M., Mduma, S. & Sinclair, A.R.E. (2006). Effective enforcement in a conservation area. Science 314, 1266.
  • Hønneland, G. (1999). A model of compliance in fisheries: theoretical foundations and practical application. Ocean Coast. Mgmt. 42, 716.
  • Horning, R. (2003). How rules affect conservation outcomes. In The natural history of Madagascar: 146153. Goodman, S.M. & Benstead, J.P. (Eds). Chicago, USA: Chicago University Press.
  • Infield, M. & Namara, A. (2001). Community attitudes and behaviour towards conservation: an assessment of a community conservation programme around Lake Mburo National Park, Uganda. Oryx 35, 4860.
  • Jachmann, H. & Billiouw, M. (1997). Elephant poaching and law enforcement in the Central Luangwa Valley, Zambia. J. Appl. Ecol. 34, 233244.
  • Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47, 263292.
  • Kaplow, L. (1990). A note on the optimal use of nonmonetary sanctions. J. Public Econ. 42, 245247.
  • Kohlberg, L. (1984). Essays on moral development. Vol. 2. San Francisco: Harper & Row.
  • Kremer, M. & Morcom, C. (2000). Elephants. Am. Econ. Rev. 90, 212234.
  • Leader-Williams, N. & Albon, S.D. (1988). Allocation of resources for conservation. Nature 336, 533535.
  • Leader-Williams, N., Albon, S.D. & Berry, P.S.M. (1990). Illegal exploitation of black rhinoceros and elephant populations – patterns of decline, law-enforcement and patrol effort in Luangwa Valley, Zambia. J. Appl. Ecol. 27, 10551087.
  • Leader-Williams, N. & Milner-Gulland, E.J. (1993). Policies for the enforcement of wildlife laws: the balance between detection and penalties in Luangwa Valley, Zambia. Conserv. Biol. 7, 611.
  • Malik, A.S. (1990). Avoidance, screening and optimum enforcement. RAND J. Econ. 21, 341353.
  • Mazany, R.L., Charles, A.T. & Cross, M.L. (1989). Fisheries regulation and incentives to overfish. In Proceedings of the Canadian Economics Association Meeting. Quebec City: Laval University.
  • McFadden, D. (1999). Rationality for economists? J. Risk Uncertainty 19, 73105.
  • De Merode, E., Smith, K., Homewood, K., Pettifor, R., Rowcliffe, M. & Cowlishaw, G. (2007). The impact of armed conflict on protected-area efficacy in central Africa. Biol. Lett. 3, 299301.
  • Mesterton-Gibbons, M. & Milner-Gulland, E.J. (1998). On the strategic stability of monitoring: implications for cooperative wildlife management programmes in Africa. Proc. Roy. Soc. Lond. Ser. B – Biol. Sci. 265, 12371244.
  • Milner-Gulland, E.J. & Leader-Williams, N. (1992). A model of incentives for the illegal exploitation of black rhinos and elephants – poaching pays in Luangwa-Valley, Zambia. J. Appl. Ecol. 29, 388401.
  • Moseley, W.G. (2001). African evidence on the relation of poverty, time preference and the environment. Ecol. Econ. 38, 317326.
  • Nielsen, J.R. (2003). An analytical framework for studying: compliance and legitimacy in fisheries management. Mar. Policy 27, 425432.
  • Nielsen, J.R. & Mathiesen, C. (2003). Important factors influencing rule compliance in fisheries lessons from Denmark. Mar. Policy 27, 409416.
  • Olsen, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.
  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Polinsky, A.M. & Shavell, S. (1979). The optimal tradeoff between the probability and magnitude of fines. Am. Econ. Rev. 69, 880891.
  • Polinsky, A.M. & Shavell, S. (1991). A note on optimal fines when wealth varies among individuals. Am. Econ. Rev. 81, 618621.
  • Robinson, E.J.Z. (2004). Wanted dead and alive: are hunting and protection of endangered species compatible? Department of Economics, University of Oxford. WPS/2004-20, Oxford.
  • Rowcliffe, J.M., De Merode, E. & Cowlishaw, G. (2004). Do wildlife laws work? Species protection and the application of a prey choice model to poaching decisions. Proc. Roy. Soc. Lond. Ser. B – Biol. Sci. 271, 26312636.
  • Salafsky, N., Margoluis, R. & Redford, K.H. (2001). Adaptive management: a tool for conservation practitioners. Washington, DC: Biodiversity Support Program.
  • Samoilys, M.A., Martin-Smith, K.M., Giles, B.G., Cabrera, G., Anticamara, J.A., Brunio, E.O. & Vincent, A.C.J. (2007). Effectiveness of five small Philippines' coral reef reserves for fish populations depends on site-specific factors, particularly enforcement history. Biol. Conserv. 136, 584601.
  • Schoemaker, P.J.H. (1982). The expected utility model: its variants, purposes, evidence and limitations. J. Econ. Literature 20, 529563.
  • Skonhoft, A. & Solstad, J.T. (1998). The political economy of wildlife exploitation. Land Econ. 74, 1631.
  • Smith, P.E. (1993). Balancing sampling precision and fisheries management: objectives, minimal methods. Bull. Mar. Sci. 53, 930935.
  • Solomon, J., Jacobson, S.K., Wald, K.D. & Gavin, M. (2007). Estimating illegal resource use at a Ugandan national park with the randomized response technique. Hum. Dimensions Wildl. 12, 7588.
  • Stigler, G.J. (1970). The optimum enforcement of laws. J. Polit. Econ. 78, 526536.
  • Stiles, D. (2004). The ivory trade and elephant conservation. Environ. Conserv. 31, 309321.
  • Sutherland, E.H. (1947). Principles of criminology. Philadelphia: Lippincott.
  • Sutinen, J.G. & Andersen, P. (1985). The economics of fisheries law-enforcement. Land Econ. 61, 387397.
  • Sutinen, J.G. & Gauvin, J.R. (1989). Assessing compliance with fishery regulations. Maritimes 33, 1012.
  • Sutinen, J.G. & Kuperan, K. (1999). A socio-economic theory of regulatory compliance. Int. J. Soc. Econ. 26, 174193.
  • Sutinen, J.G., Rieser, A. & Gauvin, J.R. (1990). Measuring and explaining noncompliance in federally managed fisheries. Ocean Development & International Law 21, 335372.
  • Tapp, J.L. & Levine, F.J. (1977). Law, justice and the individual in society: psychological and legal issues. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.
  • Tsebelis, G. (1989). The abuse of probability in political-analysis – the Robinson Crusoe fallacy. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 83, 7791.
  • Tversky, A. & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. J. Risk Uncertainty 5, 297323.
  • Tyler, T. (1990). Why people obey the law. London: Yale University Press.
  • Walmsley, S.F. & White, A.T. (2003). Influence of social, management and enforcement factors on the long-term ecological effects of marine sanctuaries. Environ. Conserv. 30, 388407.
  • Walsh, P.D., Abernethy, K.A., Bermejo, M., Beyers, R., De Wachter, P., Akou, M.E., Huijbregts, B., Mambounga, D.I., Toham, A.K., Kilbourn, A.M., Lahm, S.A., Latour, S., Maisels, F., Mbina, C., Mihindou, Y., Ndong Obiang, S., Effa, E.N., Starkey, M.P., Telfer, P., Thibault, M., Tutin, C.E.G., White, L.J.T. & Wilkie, D.S. (2003). Catastrophic ape decline in western equatorial Africa. Nature 422, 611614.
  • Weissing, F. & Ostrom, E. (1991). Crime and punishment: further reflections on the counterintuitive results of mixed equilibria games. J. Theor. Polit. 3, 343350.
  • Wells, M. (1992). Biodiversity conservation, affluence and poverty: mismatched costs and benefits and efforts to remedy them. Ambio 21, 237243.
  • Wilshusen, P.R., Brechin, S.R., Fortwangler, C.L. & West, P.C. (2002). Reinventing a square wheel: critique of a resurgent “Protection paradigm” in international biodiversity conservation. Soc. Nat. Res. 15, 1740.