Is Economic Growth Good for Investors?

Authors

  • Jay R. Ritter

    1. JAY RITTER is Cordell Professor of Finance at the University of Florida. He is best known for his research on initial public offerings, but he has published articles on many other topics as well.
    Search for more papers by this author

  • This paper updates and extends through 2011 the findings that were first presented in my 2005 Pacific-Basin Finance Journal article, “Economic Growth and Equity Returns,” which contains a more complete list of citations and references. I want to thank Leming Lin for excellent research assistance, and the editor, Don Chew, for extensive suggestions and guidance. Comments from Jeremy Siegel and participants at the TAPMI International Conference in Banking and Finance in Bangalore and seminars at the Australian National University and the University of Melbourne are also appreciated.

Abstract

When measured over long periods of time, the correlation of countries' inflation-adjusted per capita GDP growth and stock returns is negative. This result holds for both developed countries (for which the correlation coefficient is –0.39 using data from 1900–2011) and emerging markets (the correlation is –0.41 over the period 1988–2011). And this means that investors would have been better off investing in countries with lower per capita GDP growth than in countries experiencing the highest growth rates.

This seems surprising since economic growth is generally assumed to be good for corporate profits. In attempting to explain this finding, the author begins by noting that economic growth can be achieved through increased inputs of capital and labor, which don't necessarily benefit the stockholders of existing companies. Growth also comes from technological advances, which do not necessarily lead to higher profits since competition among firms often results in the benefits accruing to consumers and workers. What's more, it's important to recognize that growth has both an expected and an unexpected component. And one explanation for the negative correlation between growth and stock returns is the tendency for investors to overpay for expected growth.

But there is another—and in the author's view, a more important—part of the explanation. Along with the negative correlation between long-run average stock returns and per capita growth rates, the author also reports a strong positive association between (per share) dividend growth rates and overall stock returns. Such an association is not surprising since unusual growth in dividends is a fairly reliable predictor of increases in future earnings. But another effect at work here is the role of dividends—and, in the U.S., stock repurchases too—in limiting what might be called the corporate “overinvestment problem,” the natural tendency of corporate managers to pursue growth, if necessary at the expense of profitability. One of the main messages of this article is that corporate growth adds value only when companies reinvest their earnings in projects that are expected to earn at least their cost of capital—while at the same time committing to return excess cash and capital to their shareholders through dividends and stock buybacks.

Ancillary